Browsing
     by title


0-9 A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Q R S T U V W X Y Z

or enter first few letters:   
OK
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho benefits from air service agreements? The case of international air cargo operations
Wu, You UL; Lange, Anne UL; Mantin, Benny UL

in Transportation Research Part B: Methodological (2022), 163

Air service agreements between countries spell out diverse provisions, such as reciprocal capacity allocations. We analyze how such agreements, which regulate total capacity in markets, affect total ... [more ▼]

Air service agreements between countries spell out diverse provisions, such as reciprocal capacity allocations. We analyze how such agreements, which regulate total capacity in markets, affect total welfare and its distribution. We consider the interactions between two competing cargo airlines, their end customers, logistics service providers—who serve as intermediaries between the former two agent types—as well as the policy makers. Accounting for demand uncertainty, we model this interaction as a two-stage game. In the first stage, the policy makers coordinate equal capacity allocations to the two asset providers, whereas in the second stage, the asset providers compete over prices in the spot market. Solving the model, we characterize the pricing strategies employed by the two competing capacity-constrained asset providers in the spot market when facing price sensitive demand from end customers. We further analyze the corresponding capacity decisions. We then compare this coordinated competitive setting with a collaborative setting where the two asset providers can (virtually) merge and act as a monopoly. We find that, compared with the monopoly setting, the coordinated duopoly results in lower capacity, lower profits to the asset providers, larger benefits to both end customers and logistics service providers, and overall lower total welfare. These results suggest that policy makers shall hold an open attitude towards a higher level of cooperation among the asset providers. We carry out robustness checks to verify our insights hold with three, rather than two, asset providers, with different demand distributions, when capacity is costly and when asymmetric capacities are allowed in the spot market. [less ▲]

Detailed reference viewed: 69 (12 UL)
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho Benefits from Human Rights Treaties?
Happold, Matthew UL

in Riassetto, Isabelle; Heuschling, Luc; Ravarani, Georges (Eds.) Liber Amicorum Rusen Ergeç (2017)

This chapter examines how the question of whether legal persons (in particular corporations) enjoy human rights has been answered under a number of human rights treaties. Most human rights treaties have ... [more ▼]

This chapter examines how the question of whether legal persons (in particular corporations) enjoy human rights has been answered under a number of human rights treaties. Most human rights treaties have been interpreted as conferring rights upon natural, but not on legal, persons. And most international human rights bodies will only entertain complaints from individuals and not from corporations. But the European Court of Human Rights and the Court of Justice of the European Union have taken a quite different approach from that of other regional and sub-regional courts and the UN Human Rights Committee, viewing corporations as rights-holders under the treaties they administer. They have done so, however, largely on the basis not of any expressed philosophical disagreements but by reference to the relevant treaty texts. Grander arguments have tended to be supportive, even when extensive. This is unsurprising. If such an important distinction is to be made, it should be undertaken by the treaty drafters. But saying that legal persons can be rights-holders under human rights treaties is only a beginning. Corporations are not individuals, even though they can be analogised as such. Which leads back to the original question: when should they benefit from the same rights as individuals? Two issues arise here. The first concerns what rights corporations should enjoy: the second the extent to which they should enjoy them. In contrast to the initial question, these two issues have been left to the judges alone to determine. The justification given by the European Court of Human Rights for precluding governmental bodies or entities from bringing claims is to prevent States parties to the Convention from acting both as applicants and respondents, because it is the State itself which is obliged to guarantee respect for fundamental rights within its territory. Drilling down further, one might say that different categories of entity are holders of rights and bearers of obligations under human rights treaties. Increasingly, given the decline of the State and the rise of the corporation, we are told that human rights should serve directly to regulate corporate behaviour. Might not the same consideration lead to a need to reconsider the circumstances in which it is appropriate for corporations themselves to enjoy such rights? [less ▲]

Detailed reference viewed: 131 (4 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho benefits from partial tax coordination?
Han, Yutao UL

E-print/Working paper (2013)

In this paper, we investigate whether partial tax coordination is beneficial to <br />countries within and outside a tax union, in which countries are supposed to compete <br />in taxes and infrastructure ... [more ▼]

In this paper, we investigate whether partial tax coordination is beneficial to <br />countries within and outside a tax union, in which countries are supposed to compete <br />in taxes and infrastructure. Our results demonstrate that, a subgroup of countries <br />agreeing on a common tax rate, can harm both member and nonmember <br />states. This is in contrast to the classical findings that partial tax harmonization <br />is Pareto improving. When a minimum tax rate is imposed within a tax union, we <br />demonstrate that it does not necessarily improve the welfare of the member countries. <br />Moreover, both the high tax and low tax countries can be worse off. This <br />conclusion is at odds with the classical result that a high tax country benefits from <br />the imposition of a lower tax bound. [less ▲]

Detailed reference viewed: 53 (7 UL)
See detailWho blames the victim? Kausal- und Verantwortlichkeitszuschreibungen im Umfeld einer Krebserkrankung
Filipp, Sigrun-Heide; Ferring, Dieter UL

in U. Koch, & J. Weis (Eds.), Krankheitsbewältigung bei Krebs und Möglichkeiten der Unterstützung. Der Förderschwerpunkt "Rehabilitation von Krebskranken" (1998)

Detailed reference viewed: 111 (0 UL)
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho chooses what in the game store? The relationship between game preferences and dimensions of aggression
Happ, Christian UL; Melzer, André UL; Rossi, M. et al

Scientific Conference (2009, November)

Detailed reference viewed: 212 (2 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho Clicks There!: Anonymizing the Photographer in a Camera Saturated Society
Nagaraja, Shishir; Schaffer, Peter UL; Aouada, Djamila UL

in Workshop on Privacy in the Electronic Society (WPES) (2011)

Detailed reference viewed: 92 (2 UL)
See detailWho Decides What? Judicial Deference in International Economic Adjudication
Fahner, Johannes Hendrik UL

Presentation (2018, February 01)

Detailed reference viewed: 75 (0 UL)
See detailWho defines what the World Social Forum is?
Schröder, Christian UL

in America Latina en Movimiento (2013)

Detailed reference viewed: 74 (0 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho does not participate in elections in Europe and why is this? A multilevel analysis of social mechanisms behind non-voting
Hadjar, Andreas UL; Beck, Michael

in European Societies (2010), 12(4), 521-542

This paper focuses on the research question ‘Who does not vote and why?’ regarding national elections in 24 European countries. We analyse determinants of non-voting both on the individual and the ... [more ▼]

This paper focuses on the research question ‘Who does not vote and why?’ regarding national elections in 24 European countries. We analyse determinants of non-voting both on the individual and the societal level employing a multilevel design. On the micro level, the sociological determinants under consideration are education, cohort and gender. Regarding psychological or motivational factors, we include in the analyses political efficacy, political interest, political trust and satisfaction with politics. On the macro level, we analyse characteristics of the electoral system, including opportunities for ‘direct democracy’, maturity of democracy, disproportionality factor, and if the participation in elections is compulsory. The data source of the analyses is the European Social Survey 2006. A first main finding is the fact that the probability of non-voting is higher among people with a low level of education and among younger cohorts. The motivational factors have similar impacts on non-voting across all analysed societies. Lack of political efficacy, lack of political interest, lack of political trust and dissatisfaction with politicians and the political system increase the probability of non-voting. Regarding macro influences, countries with compulsory voting and ‘old democracies’ turn out to have a lower rate of non-voting, although these effects vanish when simultaneously modelled with the social psychological micro level indicators. [less ▲]

Detailed reference viewed: 240 (2 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho gets what in coalition governments? Predictors of portfolio allocation in parliamentary democracies
Bäck, Hanna; Debus, Marc; Dumont, Patrick UL

in European Journal of Political Research (2011), 50(4), 441-478

Ministerial portfolios are the most obvious payoffs for parties entering a governing coalition in parliamentary democracies. This renders the bargaining over portfolios an important phase of the ... [more ▼]

Ministerial portfolios are the most obvious payoffs for parties entering a governing coalition in parliamentary democracies. This renders the bargaining over portfolios an important phase of the government formation process. The question of 'who gets what, and why?' in terms of ministerial remits has not yet received much attention by coalition or party scholars. This article focuses on this qualitative aspect of portfolio allocation and uses a new comparative dataset to evaluate a number of hypotheses that can be drawn from the literature. The main hypothesis is that parties which, in their election manifestos, emphasise themes corresponding to the policy remit of specific cabinet portfolios are more likely to obtain control over these portfolios. The results show that policy saliency is indeed an important predictor of portfolio allocation in postwar Western European parliamentary democracies. [less ▲]

Detailed reference viewed: 148 (2 UL)
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho is afraid of education?
Biesta, Gert UL

in University of Tokyo Center for Philosophy Bulletin (2007), 10

Detailed reference viewed: 116 (0 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho is going to pay the price of Covid-19? Reflections about an unequal Brazil
Ribeiro, Fabiana UL; Leist, Anja UL

in International Journal for Equity in Health (2020), 19

Detailed reference viewed: 181 (20 UL)
See detailWho is there? Finding the other in the self.
Biesta, Gert UL

in Philosophy of Education Yearbook (2007)

Detailed reference viewed: 62 (2 UL)
See detailWho Loses in the Downturn? Economic Crisis, Employment and Income Distribution
Immervoll, Herwig; Peichl, Andreas; Tatsiramos, Konstantinos UL

Book published by Emerald (2011)

Detailed reference viewed: 44 (0 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho makes the pie bigger? An experimental study on co-opetition
Neugebauer, Tibor UL; Lacomba, Juan A.; Lagos, Francisco

E-print/Working paper (2010)

Detailed reference viewed: 115 (2 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho makes the Pie Bigger? An Experimental Study on Cooperation
Neugebauer, Tibor UL; Lacomba, J.-A.; Lagos, F.

in New Zealand Economic Papers (2011)

Detailed reference viewed: 60 (2 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho Makes, Who Breaks: Which Scientists Stay in Academe?
Balsmeier, Benjamin UL; Pellens, Maikel

in Economics Letters (2014), 122

Detailed reference viewed: 194 (3 UL)
See detailWho owns the land? Highlights in the history of land reform
Hertweck, Florian UL; Löhr, Dirk

in Archplus (2018), (231),

Detailed reference viewed: 47 (4 UL)
Full Text
Peer Reviewed
See detailWho owns the past? Überlegungen zur Repräsentation der Geschichte Luxemburgs während des Zweiten Weltkriegs in zwei ausgewählten Ausstellungen
Jungblut, Marie-Paule UL

in Hemecht : Zeitschrift für Luxemburger Geschichte = Revue d'Histoire Luxembourgeoise (2017), 3-4

Detailed reference viewed: 106 (6 UL)